Commentary

Commentary

 
 
Posts tagged Eurodollars
Central Bank Liquidity Swaps: A Primer

The Trump Administration’s willingness to abrogate treaties (including those negotiated under the previous Trump Administration) makes U.S. allies doubt a whole host of commitments on which they currently rely. In this post, we focus on the Federal Reserve’s central bank liquidity swaps, which provide a key backstop for global markets in dollar assets. At least twice in the past two decades, this esoteric tool played a major role in sustaining the dollar-based financial system outside the United States, thereby insulating the U.S. financial system from the default, market, and liquidity risk of foreign intermediaries.

Given the crisis-management role that the dollar swap lines play, we can think of no reason why the Fed itself would wish to end them. However, if the Administration or the Congress were to perceive the Fed swap and repo facilities as supporting only foreign institutions, or if they view these facilities as a device to influence foreign behavior, it is easy to imagine pressure on the Fed to drop these crisis prevention and crisis-management tools or to make them conditional.

In this post, we explain what the swap lines are, how they operate, and how an end to the swap lines could lead to financial instability within the United States as well as undermine the use of the dollar and dollar-denominated assets in the global financial system. We then consider how foreign central banks might insulate their banking systems against the risk that they could no longer rely on the swap lines.

Read More
Replacing LIBOR

Publication of LIBOR―the London Interbank Offered Rate―will likely cease at the end of 2021. This is the message U.K. Financial Conduct Authority (FCA) CEO Andrew Bailey sent in 2017 when he announced that, after 2021, the FCA would no longer compel reluctant banks to respond to the LIBOR survey. Given the small number of underlying LIBOR transactions, and the reputational and legal risks banks face when submitting survey responses based largely on their expert judgement, we expect that most banks will then happily retreat. In just over two years, then, the FCA could declare LIBOR rates “unrepresentative” of financial reality and it will vanish (see, for example, here).

Most financial experts know this. Yet, LIBOR remains by far the most important global benchmark interest rate, forming the basis for an estimated $400 trillion of contracts (as of mid-2018; see Schrimpf and Sushko), about one-half of which are denominated in U.S. dollars (as of end-2016; see Table 1 here). While the use of alternative reference rates is increasing rapidly, to beat the LIBOR-countdown clock, the pace will have to quicken substantially. In the United States, the outstanding notional value of derivatives linked to the alternative secured overnight reference rate (SOFR) jumped from less than $100 billion to more than $9 trillion in just the past year (see SIFMA primer). Yet, this amount still represents a small fraction of outstanding dollar-LIBOR-linked instruments.

In this post, we examine the U.S. dollar LIBOR transition process, highlighting both the substantial progress and the major obstacles that still lie ahead. The key goal of the transition is to ensure that the inevitable cessation of LIBOR does not trigger system-wide disruptions. Unfortunately, at this stage, count us among those that remain deeply concerned….

Read More
Ten Years After Bear

Ten years ago this week, the run on Bear Stearns kicked off the second of three phases of the Great Financial Crisis (GFC) of 2007-2009. In an earlier post, we argued that the crisis began in earnest on August 9, 2007, when BNP Paribas suspended redemptions from three mutual funds invested in U.S. subprime mortgage debt. In that first phase of the crisis, the financial strains reflected a scramble for liquidity combined with doubts about the capital adequacy of a widening circle of intermediaries.

In responding to the run on Bear, the Federal Reserve transformed itself into a modern version of Bagehot’s lender of last resort (LOLR) directed at managing a pure liquidity crisis (see, for example, Madigan). Consequently, in the second phase of the GFC—in the period between Bear’s March 14 rescue and the September 15 failure of Lehman—the persistence of financial strains was, in our view, primarily an emerging solvency crisis. In the third phase, following Lehman’s collapse, the focus necessarily turned to recapitalization of the financial system—far beyond the role (or authority) of any LOLR.

In this post, we trace the evolution of the Federal Reserve during the period between Paribas and Bear, as it became a Bagehot LOLR. This sets the stage for a future analysis of the solvency issues that threatened to convert the GFC into another Great Depression.

Read More